Climate science research is rigged: but what about economics?

Walter Block
Loyola University New Orleans
Joseph A. Butt, S.J. College of Business
wblock@loyno.edu

Climate science research is rigged: but what about economics?

ABSTRACT

Recent discoveries have revealed that there is intellectual bias in the field of climate science; the present paper makes the case that this moral and intellectual rot has also affected the field of economics.

I. Introduction 

It is by now clear to everyone that all is not well in the field of climate science. Recent events have demonstrated that when it comes to scientific open mindedness (Gold, 1989), buttressed by double blind refereeing and peer review, something is rotten in the state of temperature measurement. (1) No longer can we take claims from mainstream climatologists to the effect that we are now experiencing man made global warming, without buckets and buckets of salt. Skeptics and “deniers” have now been given a shot in the arm because of this disgraceful intellectual hanky-panky. (2)

What about economics? Particularly, I ask, has the Austro-libertarian movement been victimized by similar shenanigans? Although there is no similar “smoking gun,” there would appear to be at least some prima facie evidence in support of this contention: we are now suffering in the midst of economic doldrums. Opinions differ as to whether we are in the throes of merely a serious recession or the second coming of the Great Depression, but, whatever the situation, it is clear that none of the main stream schools of economic thought − Keynesian, neoclassical, monetarist, New Classical/rational expectations, New Keynesian, Real Business Cycles, Stochastic Dynamic General Equilibrium − have a clue as to the genesis of this misery, nor what to do about solving the problem. And yet, the Austrians, the only ones to whom such a negative assessment does not apply, have been all but frozen out of the public discussion (3) by the mainstream media. The Austrian or praxeological school is, as it were, the economic equivalent of “deniers” or skeptics.

Why is this?

There are two prominent viewpoints within the Austro-libertarian movement that attempt to explain this sad state of affairs. The first, mainly associated with initially with Israel Kirzner, and, now, also, with Peter Boettke, is that we have tried our best, but, with a few exceptions, we have been found wanting. We the followers of Menger, Mises and Hayek must simply do better work if our analysis is to be accepted by the scholarly community. We must show them that our insights help explain economic reality, and we have usually fallen down on the job. But the gatekeepers of the profession, editors and referees of the prestigious publications, and members of the economics departments at the top schools such as Harvard, MIT, Columbia, NYU, Chicago, Berkeley, Stanford, etc., are open minded. When and if we do get our act together, our colleague economists representing other schools of thought will judge our output fairly, and accept it if it is good.

The alternative explanation was propounded by Murray Rothbard when he created the Review of Austrian Economics (the successor journal is now the Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics). The editor of the latter, Joseph Salerno, is now perhaps the most prominent articulator of this critical viewpoint. (4) The perspective that arises from this quarter is that there is chicanery afoot; prestige in the economics profession is based on publication in the leading journals, such as the American Economic Review, the Journal of Political Economy, and others of that ilk. But the editors and referees of those journals see Austrianism as a cult, or a religion, and with but very few exceptions refuse to publish the findings of members of this school of economic thought. The Rothbard founded the RAE because of this very fact: Austrians were all but barred from mainstream “prestigious” journals. (5)

There is some evidence in support of the optimistic hypothesis. There are, after all, a few Austrians who have managed to publish in the top journals. (6)  However, several of them are merely short notes, or replies, not full length articles (Garrison, 1985; Kirzner, 1963; Rothbard, 1951a, 1951b). One of them appeared in Papers and Proceedings, not in the “main” section of the journal (Anderson and Hill, 1967). Some of them are Austrians only if a rather inclusive definition of this term is employed (Heiner, 1983; Frech, 1976). Some of these were written by Austrians, but the article in question had nothing to do with this school of thought, and could have been written by a (very gifted) neoclassical economist (Leeson, 2007). (7)  Some of them are criticisms of other Austrian economists (Cowen (8)  and Fink, 1985), something to which the mainstream, according to this critical hypothesis, would not be adverse. (9)  One is struck by the paucity of the number of such publications, since there have been dozens, scores, maybe even hundreds of Austrians actively publishing (10) since then, particularly after 1974, the year of the awarding of the Nobel Prize in economics to F. A. Hayek. (11)

II. Evidence 

In my assessment, if there is some very limited support for the Panglossian hypothesis, there is much more for the more critical realistic one. Consider the following points. 

1. The “Review of Austrian Economics” 

Exhibit A in this regard may well be the introduction to the first issue of the Review of Austrian Economics. State its editors (Rothbard and Block, 1987, xi): “The existence of the Review of Austrian Economics will resolve some dilemmas now faced by Austrian-oriented researchers who attempt to publish in the mainline journals. Articles that simply assume a familiarity on the part of the profession with methodological norms and theoretical developments within the Austrian tradition are unlikely to be published; the profession, by and large, has no such familiarity. Articles that devote substantial space to stating and defending the methodological norms and retracing the theoretical development are also unlikely to be published; they are seen, and correctly so, as unoriginal. Articles whose backgrounds are extensive in absolute terms but brief in relation to the remainder of the article do not constitute a workable compromise; they are rejected on the basis of length. These constraints do not totally preclude the publication of Austrian-oriented articles in mainline journals, but they make such events much more difficult. The Review of Austrian Economics will allow the praxeologically oriented researcher to assume a certain familiarity with the Austrian literature on the part of its readers.”

Note the cordial tone of these authors. Bias against the praxeological school nowhere appears in this “Introductory Editorial.” Even apart from that, though, as we can see, there are strong barriers against the acceptance of Austrian analysis in the pages of mainstream journals. “Doing good work” will scarcely overcome them.

2. The Social Science Citation Index (SSCI) 

Klein and Chiang (2005) state: “Thus, the SSCI is an important component in the academic apparatus of rank and prestige. Those who decide which journals are to be included in the SSCI exercise an enormous influence over the social sciences. But surprisingly little scrutiny has been given to SSCI and its journal selection process—I have searched on “SSCI” in ISI’s own Web of Science and found little pertinent to this investigation. In fact, in reading the scientometricians, including the economists who work with citation data, one perceives an attitude that Citation is of a divine and immaculate nature. The researchers who work with citation data almost never so much as raise a question about who is making the all-important decisions about journal inclusion, how they make those decisions, and whether they are fair or reasonable. This paper seems to be the first critical examination of SSCI.”

These authors have uncovered a sort of intellectual “Catch 22” which works to the detriment of the Austrian School. Prestige of the economics departments of universities is based to a significant degree upon the prestige of the scholarly journals in which they publish. And who are the gatekeepers (the editors and referees) of the latter? Why, members of the former.

3. Other biases 

According to Holcombe (2004) “… economists working in the Austrian tradition seem to be more inclined to publish their ideas in books rather than journal articles, perhaps creating a bias against such scholars. There are two journals aimed explicitly at publishing Austrian economics, The Review of Austrian Economics and The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, but neither is in the ISI/SSCI database. For obvious reasons, this could push young scholars interested in the ideas of the Austrian school, but hoping to achieve tenure at a research university, toward doing more mainstream types of research.”

I think this author, in an attempt to be measured, understates the matter. I would go further. I do not think that such a phenomenon merely “could” push young scholars, and, indeed, all academics interested in tenure and promotion, in a non Austrian direction; I would maintain that it does, and has done in the past. While I have no data to support this contention, I rest my case (12) on the nature of demand curves to be downward sloping.

4. The Fed rears its ugly head 

Consider the sad story of the Fed’s takeover of large parts of the economics profession (Higgs, 2009; Grim, 2009, Auerbach, 2008), particularly that aspect of it concerned with monetary, banking and business cycle analysis. The central bank of the U.S. has practically turned monetary economists into a totally (well, largely) owned subsidiary of itself. According to Grim (2009): “Auerbach (2008) found that in 1992, roughly 968 members of the AEA designated “domestic monetary and financial theory and institutions” as their primary field, and 717 designated it as their secondary field. Combining his numbers with the current ones from the AEA and NABE, it’s fair to conclude that there are something like 1,000 to 1,500 monetary economists working across the country. Add up the 220 economist jobs at the Board of Governors along with regional bank hires and contracted economists, and the Fed employs or contracts with easily 500 economists at any given time. Add in those who have previously worked for the Fed − or who hope to one day soon − and you’ve accounted for a very significant majority of the field.”

It is a veritable staple of the dismal science that businessmen often put their private interests over that of others. Public choice economists call this “rent seeking.” (13) Perhaps Smith (1776) said it best: “Seldom do businessmen of the same trade get together but that it results in some detriment to the general public.” It would appear that this moral failing applies not only to commercial interests, but to academic economists as well. These purchased mainstream monetary economists are not stupid. (14) They know on which side of their bread the butter is to be found: on the Fed side.

5. Sherwin Rosen 

Rosen (1997) threw down the gauntlet at the Austrians. He asks the question: “Austrian and Neoclassical Economics: Any Gains from Trade?,” and answers that if there are any at all, they are pretty paltry. So much so, that members of this school of thought would do well not to set up their own refereed journals, and, instead, abide by the assessment of the mainstream as to the value of their intellectual contribution. (15)

Why? Because they have lost the “market test” of truth; there are, after all, more neoclassical economists now practicing, than there are members of the praxeological school. In response to this sally, Yeager (1997, p. 159) replies to Rosen (1997): “He evidently holds it against the Austrians that they do not pass his market test in the intellectual atmosphere created by members of his own camp, an atmosphere pervaded by narrow yet tacit methodological preaching.” 

Rosen (1997) insists that the Austrians play by the rules set up by members of his own school of economics, acknowledge the legitimacy of neoclassical editors and referees, and not try to set up their own alternative institutions. How is this different from the manner in which Prof. Jones treats the global warming deniers? Consider the following gem: “In one e-mail, the center’s director, Phil Jones, writes Pennsylvania State University’s Michael E. Mann and questions whether the work of academics that question the link between human activities and global warming deserve to make it into the prestigious IPCC report, which represents the global consensus view on climate science.

“‘I can’t see either of these papers being in the next IPCC report,’ Jones writes. ‘Kevin and I will keep them out somehow–even if we have to redefine what the peer-review literature is!’

“In another, Jones and Mann discuss how they can pressure an academic journal not to accept the work of climate skeptics with whom they disagree. ‘Perhaps we should encourage our colleagues in the climate research community to no longer submit to, or cite papers in, this journal,’ Mann writes. . . .” (16)

Yes, to be sure there are differences in the two cases. The freezing out of the economics “deniers” is far more subtle and implicit than in the case of environmentalism. And, also, it looks as if the former will far more longer endure than the latter, which is now the subject of widespread disgust and derision. 

III. Conclusion 

There is reason to believe that there are strong parallels between the mainstream economists’ treatment of the Austrian School of Economics, and the mainstream school of environmentalism’s treatment of the Anthropogenic Global Warming “deniers.” While there is now an uncovered smoking gun in the latter but not the former case, there is enough evidence in the economic realm to seriously consider this hypothesis.

References: 

Anderson, Terry and P.J. Hill, 1967. “The Evolution of Property Rights,” American Economic Review, papers and proceedings

Anderson, William L. 2009. “The Meaning of ‘Climategate,’“ December 7; http://www.lewrockwell.com/anderson/anderson272.html

Anderson, William L. 2000. “Austrian Economics and the ‘Market Test’: A Comment on Laband and Tollison.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 3(3): 63-73. Appraisal.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 3(1): 43-48.

Auerbach, Robert D. 2008. Deception and Abuse at the Fed: Henry B. Gonzalez Battles Alan Greenspan’s Bank; Austin, TX: University of Texas Press

Barnett, William and Walter Block. 2010. “Mises never used demand curves; was he wrong? Ignorant? No: The Antimathematicality of Demand Curves.” Dialogue, Vol. 1, pp. 23-31; March; http://www.uni-svishtov.bg/dialog/2010/1.10.WB.pdf

Barnett, William II and Walter Block. 2006. “Tyler Cowen on Austrian Business Cycle Theory: A Critique.” New Perspectives on Political Economy, Vol. 2, No. 2, pp. 26-84; http://pcpe.libinst.cz/nppe/2_2/nppe2_2_2.pdf; http://pcpe.libinst.cz/nppe/

Block, Walter, Christopher Westley and Alex Padilla. 2008. “Internal vs. external explanations: a new perspective on the history of economic thought,” Procesos De Mercado: Revista Europea De Economia Politica; issue 2, pp. 35-132; http://dialnet.unirioja.es/servlet/listaarticulos?tipo_busqueda=EJEMPLAR&revista_busqueda=6790&c lave_busqueda=217457 

Block, Walter. 1999. “Austrian Theorizing, Recalling the Foundations: Reply to Caplan,” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol. 2, No. 4, winter, pp. 21-39; http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae2_4_2.pdf
errata: http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae2_4_9.pdf 

Block, Walter. 2000A. “Watch Your Language,” February 21; http://www.mises.org/fullarticle.asp?control=385&month=17&title=Watch+Your+Language&id=19

Block, Walter. 2000B. Austrian Journals: A Critique of Rosen, Yeager, Laband and Tollison and Vedder and Gallaway,” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol. 3, No. 2, Summer, pp. 45-61; http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae3_2_4.pdf

Block, Walter. 2003. “Realism: Austrian vs. Neoclassical Economics, Reply to Caplan,” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol. 6, No. 3, Fall, pp. 63-76; http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae6_3_4.pdf

Block, Walter. 2005. “Rejoinder to Caplan on Bayesian Economics,” Journal of Libertarian Studies. Vol. 19, No. 1, Winter, pp. 79-95; http://blog.mises.org/blog/archives/003654.asp

Block, Walter. 2007. “Reply to Caplan on Austrian Economic Methodology” Corporate Ownership & Control, Vol. 4, No. 2, November, pp. 312-325.

Booker, Christopher. 2009. “Climategate reveals ‘the most influential tree in the world,’“ December 5; http://www.telegraph.co.uk/comment/columnists/christopherbooker/6738111/Climategate-reveals-themost-influential-tree-in-the-world.html

Buchanan, James M. and G.F. Thirlby. 1981. L.S.E. Essays on Cost, New York: New York University Press.

Buchanan, James M. 1969. Cost and Choice: An Inquiry into Economic Theory, Chicago: Markham

Callahan, Gene. 2003. “Choice and Preference,” February 10; http://mises.org/story/1163

Caplan, Bryan. 1999. “The Austrian Search for Realistic Foundations,” Southern Economic Journal, April, Vol. 65, No. 4, pp. 823-838; http://www.gmu.edu/departments/economics/bcaplan/ausfin2.doc

Carilli, Anthony M., and Dempster, Gregory M. 2003. “A note on the treatment of uncertainty in economics and finance” Journal of Education for Business 79.2 Nov. 1, pp. 99-103.

Cowen, Tyler and Kroszner, Randy. 1987. “The Development of the New Monetary Economics,” Journal of Political Economy, 93 (3): 567-590.

Cowen, Tyler and Richard Fink. 1985. “Inconsistent Equilibrium Constructs: The Evenly Rotating Economy of Mises and Rothbard.” American Economic Review, Volume 75, Number 4, September, pp. 866-869

Frech III, H.E. 1976. “The Property Rights Theory of the Firm: Empirical Results from a Natural Experiment.” Journal of Political Economy 84, no. 1 (February): 143-152 

Garrison, Roger W. 1985.”Predictable Behavior: Comment,” American Economic Review, 75(3) June, pp. 576-78; http://www.auburn.edu/~garriro/j7rheiner.html;
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1814830

Gold, Thomas. 1989. “The inertia of scientific thought.” Speculations in Science and Technology, Vol. 12, No. 4, p. 245-253, reprinted as: “New ideas in science” Journal of Scientific Exploration, Vol. 3, No. 2, p 103 – 112; http://www.suppressedscience.net/inertiaofscientificthought.html 

Grim, Ryan. 2009. “Priceless: How The Federal Reserve Bought The Economics Profession.” October 23; http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2009/09/07/priceless-how-the-federal_n_278805.html 

Heiner, Ronald. 1983. “The Origin of Predictable Behavior,” American Economic Review, 73:560-595 

Higgs, Robert. 2009. A Reader’s Guide to Bernanke’s Preemptive Attack.” November 30; http://www.lewrockwell.com/higgs/higgs137.html 

Holcombe, Randall G. 2004. “The National Research Council Ranking of Research Universities: Its Impact on Research in Economics.” Econ Journal Watch, Vol. 1, No. 3, December, pp. 498-514; http://www.econjournalwatch.org/pdf/HolcombeInvestigating1December2004.pdf 

Hoppe, Hans Hermann. 2005. “Must Austrians Embrace Indifference?,” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol. 8, No. 4, Winter, pp. 87-91; http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae8_4_6.pdf 

Hoppe, Hans Hermann. 2007. “The limits of numerical probability: Frank H. Knight and Ludwig von Mises and the frequency interpretation.” The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, vol. 10, no. 1, spring: 3–21; http://mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae10_1_1.pdf 

Hülsmann, Jörg Guido. 1999. “Economic Science and Neoclassicism.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol. 2, Num. 4, pp. 1-20; http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae2_4_1.pdf 

Kirzner, Israel M. 1963. “Reply.” Journal of Political Economy. February. 82-85. 

Kirzner, Israel, M. 1962. “Rational Action and Economic Theory,” Journal of Political Economy. August. 380-385. 

Klein, Daniel B., with Erich Chiang. 2005. “The Social Science Citation Index: A Black Box –with an Ideological Bias?” Econ Journal Watch. Vol. 1, No. 1, April, pp. 134-165; http://www.econjournalwatch.org/pdf/Klein-Chiang%20Investigating%20April%202004.pdf 

Laband, David N. and Robert D. Tollison. 2000. “On Secondhandism and Scientific 

Leeson, Peter T. 2007. “An-arrgh-chy: The Law and Economics of Pirate Organization,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 115, No. 6, pp. 1049-1094

Lott, John. 2009. “Surprise, Surprise, Many Scientists Disagree On Global Warming,” December 8; http://www.foxnews.com/opinion/2009/12/08/john-lott-climate-gate-global-warming-east-anglia/ 

Machaj, Mateusz. 2007. “A Praxeological Case for Homogeneity and Indifference.” New Perspectives on Political Economy, Vol. 3, No. 2, pp. 231 – 238; http://pcpe.libinst.cz/nppe/3_2/nppe3_2_5.pdf 

Machlup, Fritz. 1967. “Theories of the Firm: Marginalist, Behavioral, Managerial,” American Economic Review, 57:1-33 

Murphy, Robert P. 2008. “Austrian Realists.” July 17; http://mises.org/story/3028 

Murphy, Robert P., Robert Wutscher and Walter E. Block. 2010. “Mathematics in Economics: An Austrian Methodological Critique.” Philosophical Investigations, January, Vol. 33, No 1, pp. 44-66; http://www3.interscience.wiley.com/cgi-bin/fulltext/123209256/PDFSTART 

North, Gary. 2009. “The Myth of Neutral Academic Peer Review Exploded.” December 9; http://www.lewrockwell.com/north/north791.html 

Rockwell, Llewellyn H., Jr. 2009 “The Left Fell into the Climate Morass,” December 7; http://www.lewrockwell.com/rockwell/lost-left-climate-morass136.html 

Rosen, Sherwin. 1997. “Austrian and Neoclassical Economics: Any Gains from Trade?” The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 11(4): 139-152; http://www.econ.ucla.edu/doepke/teaching/resources/e202ros.pdf 

Rothbard, Murray N. 1951a. “Mises’ ‘Human Action’: Comment.” American Economic Review, Vol. 41 No. 1: 181-185. 

Rothbard, Murray N. 1951b. “Praxeology: Reply to Mr. Schuller.” American Economic Review Vol. 41 No. 5: 943-946. 

Rothbard, M. N. [1962] 1993, Man, Economy, and State (Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL.). 

Rothbard, Murray N., and Walter Block. 1987. “Introductory Editorial,” The Review of Austrian Economics, Vol. 1, 1987, pp. xi-xiii; http://mises.org/journals/rae/pdf/RAE1_1_1.pdf 

Salerno, Joseph. 2002. “The Rebirth of Austrian Economics–in Light of Austrian Economics.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics. Vol. 5, No. 4, pp. 111-128, Winter; http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae5_4_8.pdf 

Stringham, Edward, and White, Mark. 2004. ”Economic Analysis of Tort Law: Austrian and Kantian Perspectives” in Law and Economics: Alternative Economic Approaches to Legal and Regulatory Issues, Margaret Oppenheimer and Nicholas Mercuro (editors) New York: M.E. Sharpe, 374-92. http://www.sjsu.edu/stringham/docs/Stringham-and-White2005.pdf 

Stringham, Edward. 2001. “Kaldor-Hicks Efficiency and the Problem of Central Planning” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, Vol. 4, No. 2 (Summer) 41-50; http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae4_2_3.pdf 

Stringham, Edward. 2008. “Economic Value and Cost Are Subjective” in The Handbook of Austrian Economics, Peter Boettke (editor), Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, http://mises.org/journals/scholar/stringham4.pdf 

Thornton, Mark. 2004. “Does Academic Publishing Pass the Real Market Test?,” Public Choice, Springer, vol. 120(1_2), pages 41-61, 07. 

Vedder, R. and L. Gallaway. 2000. “The Austrian Market Share in the Marketplace for Ideas, 1871- 2025.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 3(1): 33-42; http://www.mises.org/journals/qjae/pdf/qjae3_1_3.pdf 

White, Lawrence H. 1984. “Competitive Payments Systems and the Unit of Account,” American Economic Review, 74(4) September, 699-712 

Yeager, L. B. 2000. “The Tactics of Secondhandism.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 3(3): 51-61 

Yeager, Leland. 1997. “Austrian Economics, Neoclassicism, and the Market Test,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 4, Fall 1997, pp. 153-163 

Notes

(1) Anderson, 2009; Booker, 2009; Lott, 2009; North, 2009; Rockwell, 2009 

(2) See the following in this regard: http://www.lewrockwell.com/spl/settled-science.html; http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703499404574559630382048494.html?mod=djemEditorialPage; http://www.lewrockwell.com/spl/new-zealand-climategate.html; http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704342404574576073505546070.html?mod=djemEditorialPage; http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704779704574552533758682774.html; http://www.blogowogo.com/blog_article.php?aid=2491499; http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704107104574572093483921568.html?mod=djemEditorialPage; http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704342404574578012533089846.html?mod=djemEditorialPage; http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704342404574576073505546070.html?mod=djemEditorialPage 

(3) For a few exceptions that prove the rule, see http://online.barrons.com/article/SB125452487696260701.html; http://online.barrons.com/article/SB125815706103247805.html; http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704471504574443600711779692.html 

(4) Dan Klein (see Klein and Chiang, 2005), editor of EconJournal Watch also deserves mention in this regard. 

(5) The position of Peter Boettke is more than passing curious. On the one hand, he buys into the notion that it is not the fault of an unfair mainstream that Austrians do not get more of a hearing within the profession. The recipe is for Austrians to do more and better research. When they do, they will be welcomed with open arms by the neoclassicals. There is this no need for refereed journals specifically created to promote Austrian research, on the ground that the mainstream will not appreciate it. On the other hand, he serves as editor of RAE, a refereed journal as its name implies, devoted to focusing on Austrian economics. Who says contradictions can’t exist in nature? 

(6) We are now discussing modern Austrians, who I operationally define as published after 1950. BohmBawerk and Hayek, for example, were regular publishers in this literature. See for example, Anderson and Hill, 1967; Cowen and Fink, 1985; Cowen and Kroszner, 1987; Frech, 1976; Garrison, 1985; Heiner, 1983; Kirzner, 1962, 1963; Leeson, 2007; Machlup, 1967; Rothbard, 1951a, 1951b; White, 1984. 

(7) As but one indication of this phenomenon, Leeson, 2009 (a book length expansion of Leeson, 2007) is very light on Austrianism. In Leeson, 2009, prominent mention is made of leading neoclassical economists such as Daron Acemoglu, Gary Becker, James Buchanan, Ronald Coase, G. Warren Nutter, Charles Tiebout, Gordon Tullock. To be sure, Hayek is treated in a similar manner, but among the missing, at least from the index, are Austrians Eugen Bohm-Bawerk, Hans Hermann Hoppe, Israel Kirzner, Carl Menger and Murray N. Rothbard; Ludwig von Mises’s “Socialism” is mentioned on p. 180, and in the index, but does not appear in the footnote section. Buchanan was an Austrian economist when he wrote Buchanan, (1969) and Buchanan and Thirlby (1981), but has subsequently renounced the praxeological school as a “cult.”

(8) Cowen’s Austrian credentials have been called into question by Barnett and Block, 2006. 

(9) Caplan (1999), although not appearing in a top journal, is another case on point regarding the publication of attacks on Austrianism appearing mainstream journals. Interestingly, the Southern Economic Journal rejected several rejoinders to Caplan (Block, 1999, Hulsmann, 1999), which were then published elsewhere, mainly in “movement” Austrian scholarly periodicals. It is not too extreme a hypothesis to claim that without these other journals, Caplan’s attack would have gone unanswered in the scholarly literature. See on this: Block, 1999, 2003, 2005, 2007; Callahan, 2003; Carilli and Dempster, 2003; Hoppe, 2005, 2007; Hulsmann, 1999; Machaj, 2007; Murphy, 2008; Murphy, Wutscher and Block, 2010; Stringham, 2001, 2008; Stringham and White, 2004. 

(10) It would be ideal to know the rejection rate for Austrians and non Austrians in the mainstream academic literature. Unfortunately, no such statistics are available. 

(11) Salerno (2002), however, correctly in my view, dates the renaissance of praxeology not to this year, but rather to about a decade earlier, the year of first publication of Rothbard (1962). 

(12) As the co-author of Barnett and Block (2010), I cannot rest my case too strongly on this consideration. 

(13) For a critique of this nomenclature, but not of the underlying concept, see Block (2000A).

(14) They are merely evil to the extent they allow their analysis and conclusions to be determined by whoever it is that is paying the piper and calling the tune. 

(15) Critics of Austrianism include Rosen (1997), Vedder and Gallaway (2000) and Laband and Tollison (2000); see rejoinders by Anderson (2000), Block (2000), Block Westley and Padilla, 2008; Thornton, 2004; Yeager (1997, 2000)

(16) http://www.therightreasons.net/index.php?/topic/17429-green-totalitarianism/ 

Facebook
Twitter
LinkedIn
Walter Block

Walter Block

Walter Block is the Harold E. Wirth Eminent Scholar Endowed Chair in Economics at Loyola University, senior fellow of the Mises Institute, and regular columnist for LewRockwell.com.

Leave a Reply